- Source: Geometric Brownian motion
A geometric Brownian motion (GBM) (also known as exponential Brownian motion) is a continuous-time stochastic process in which the logarithm of the randomly varying quantity follows a Brownian motion (also called a Wiener process) with drift. It is an important example of stochastic processes satisfying a stochastic differential equation (SDE); in particular, it is used in mathematical finance to model stock prices in the Black–Scholes model.
Technical definition: the SDE
A stochastic process St is said to follow a GBM if it satisfies the following stochastic differential equation (SDE):
d
S
t
=
μ
S
t
d
t
+
σ
S
t
d
W
t
{\displaystyle dS_{t}=\mu S_{t}\,dt+\sigma S_{t}\,dW_{t}}
where
W
t
{\displaystyle W_{t}}
is a Wiener process or Brownian motion, and
μ
{\displaystyle \mu }
('the percentage drift') and
σ
{\displaystyle \sigma }
('the percentage volatility') are constants.
The former parameter is used to model deterministic trends, while the latter parameter models unpredictable events occurring during the motion.
Solving the SDE
For an arbitrary initial value S0 the above SDE has the analytic solution (under Itô's interpretation):
S
t
=
S
0
exp
(
(
μ
−
σ
2
2
)
t
+
σ
W
t
)
.
{\displaystyle S_{t}=S_{0}\exp \left(\left(\mu -{\frac {\sigma ^{2}}{2}}\right)t+\sigma W_{t}\right).}
The derivation requires the use of Itô calculus. Applying Itô's formula leads to
d
(
ln
S
t
)
=
(
ln
S
t
)
′
d
S
t
+
1
2
(
ln
S
t
)
″
d
S
t
d
S
t
=
d
S
t
S
t
−
1
2
1
S
t
2
d
S
t
d
S
t
{\displaystyle d(\ln S_{t})=(\ln S_{t})'dS_{t}+{\frac {1}{2}}(\ln S_{t})''\,dS_{t}\,dS_{t}={\frac {dS_{t}}{S_{t}}}-{\frac {1}{2}}\,{\frac {1}{S_{t}^{2}}}\,dS_{t}\,dS_{t}}
where
d
S
t
d
S
t
{\displaystyle dS_{t}\,dS_{t}}
is the quadratic variation of the SDE.
d
S
t
d
S
t
=
σ
2
S
t
2
d
W
t
2
+
2
σ
S
t
2
μ
d
W
t
d
t
+
μ
2
S
t
2
d
t
2
{\displaystyle dS_{t}\,dS_{t}\,=\,\sigma ^{2}\,S_{t}^{2}\,dW_{t}^{2}+2\sigma S_{t}^{2}\mu \,dW_{t}\,dt+\mu ^{2}S_{t}^{2}\,dt^{2}}
When
d
t
→
0
{\displaystyle dt\to 0}
,
d
t
{\displaystyle dt}
converges to 0 faster than
d
W
t
{\displaystyle dW_{t}}
,
since
d
W
t
2
=
O
(
d
t
)
{\displaystyle dW_{t}^{2}=O(dt)}
. So the above infinitesimal can be simplified by
d
S
t
d
S
t
=
σ
2
S
t
2
d
t
{\displaystyle dS_{t}\,dS_{t}\,=\,\sigma ^{2}\,S_{t}^{2}\,dt}
Plugging the value of
d
S
t
{\displaystyle dS_{t}}
in the above equation and simplifying we obtain
ln
S
t
S
0
=
(
μ
−
σ
2
2
)
t
+
σ
W
t
.
{\displaystyle \ln {\frac {S_{t}}{S_{0}}}=\left(\mu -{\frac {\sigma ^{2}}{2}}\,\right)t+\sigma W_{t}\,.}
Taking the exponential and multiplying both sides by
S
0
{\displaystyle S_{0}}
gives the solution claimed above.
Arithmetic Brownian Motion
The process for
X
t
=
ln
S
t
S
0
{\displaystyle X_{t}=\ln {\frac {S_{t}}{S_{0}}}}
, satisfying the SDE
d
X
t
=
(
μ
−
σ
2
2
)
d
t
+
σ
d
W
t
,
{\displaystyle dX_{t}=\left(\mu -{\frac {\sigma ^{2}}{2}}\,\right)dt+\sigma dW_{t}\,,}
or more generally the process solving the SDE
d
X
t
=
m
d
t
+
v
d
W
t
,
{\displaystyle dX_{t}=m\,dt+v\,dW_{t}\,,}
where
m
{\displaystyle m}
and
v
>
0
{\displaystyle v>0}
are real constants and for an initial condition
X
0
{\displaystyle X_{0}}
, is called an Arithmetic Brownian Motion (ABM). This was the model postulated by Louis Bachelier in 1900 for stock prices, in the first published attempt to model Brownian motion, known today as Bachelier model. As was shown above, the ABM SDE can be obtained through the logarithm of a GBM via Itô's formula. Similarly, a GBM can be obtained by exponentiation of an ABM through Itô's formula.
Properties of GBM
The above solution
S
t
{\displaystyle S_{t}}
(for any value of t) is a log-normally distributed random variable with expected value and variance given by
E
(
S
t
)
=
S
0
e
μ
t
,
{\displaystyle \operatorname {E} (S_{t})=S_{0}e^{\mu t},}
Var
(
S
t
)
=
S
0
2
e
2
μ
t
(
e
σ
2
t
−
1
)
.
{\displaystyle \operatorname {Var} (S_{t})=S_{0}^{2}e^{2\mu t}\left(e^{\sigma ^{2}t}-1\right).}
They can be derived using the fact that
Z
t
=
exp
(
σ
W
t
−
1
2
σ
2
t
)
{\displaystyle Z_{t}=\exp \left(\sigma W_{t}-{\frac {1}{2}}\sigma ^{2}t\right)}
is a martingale, and that
E
[
exp
(
2
σ
W
t
−
σ
2
t
)
∣
F
s
]
=
e
σ
2
(
t
−
s
)
exp
(
2
σ
W
s
−
σ
2
s
)
,
∀
0
≤
s
<
t
.
{\displaystyle \operatorname {E} \left[\exp \left(2\sigma W_{t}-\sigma ^{2}t\right)\mid {\mathcal {F}}_{s}\right]=e^{\sigma ^{2}(t-s)}\exp \left(2\sigma W_{s}-\sigma ^{2}s\right),\quad \forall 0\leq s
The probability density function of
S
t
{\displaystyle S_{t}}
is:
f
S
t
(
s
;
μ
,
σ
,
t
)
=
1
2
π
1
s
σ
t
exp
(
−
(
ln
s
−
ln
S
0
−
(
μ
−
1
2
σ
2
)
t
)
2
2
σ
2
t
)
.
{\displaystyle f_{S_{t}}(s;\mu ,\sigma ,t)={\frac {1}{\sqrt {2\pi }}}\,{\frac {1}{s\sigma {\sqrt {t}}}}\,\exp \left(-{\frac {\left(\ln s-\ln S_{0}-\left(\mu -{\frac {1}{2}}\sigma ^{2}\right)t\right)^{2}}{2\sigma ^{2}t}}\right).}
When deriving further properties of GBM, use can be made of the SDE of which GBM is the solution, or the explicit solution given above can be used. For example, consider the stochastic process log(St). This is an interesting process, because in the Black–Scholes model it is related to the log return of the stock price. Using Itô's lemma with f(S) = log(S) gives
d
log
(
S
)
=
f
′
(
S
)
d
S
+
1
2
f
″
(
S
)
S
2
σ
2
d
t
=
1
S
(
σ
S
d
W
t
+
μ
S
d
t
)
−
1
2
σ
2
d
t
=
σ
d
W
t
+
(
μ
−
σ
2
/
2
)
d
t
.
{\displaystyle {\begin{alignedat}{2}d\log(S)&=f'(S)\,dS+{\frac {1}{2}}f''(S)S^{2}\sigma ^{2}\,dt\\[6pt]&={\frac {1}{S}}\left(\sigma S\,dW_{t}+\mu S\,dt\right)-{\frac {1}{2}}\sigma ^{2}\,dt\\[6pt]&=\sigma \,dW_{t}+(\mu -\sigma ^{2}/2)\,dt.\end{alignedat}}}
It follows that
E
log
(
S
t
)
=
log
(
S
0
)
+
(
μ
−
σ
2
/
2
)
t
{\displaystyle \operatorname {E} \log(S_{t})=\log(S_{0})+(\mu -\sigma ^{2}/2)t}
.
This result can also be derived by applying the logarithm to the explicit solution of GBM:
log
(
S
t
)
=
log
(
S
0
exp
(
(
μ
−
σ
2
2
)
t
+
σ
W
t
)
)
=
log
(
S
0
)
+
(
μ
−
σ
2
2
)
t
+
σ
W
t
.
{\displaystyle {\begin{alignedat}{2}\log(S_{t})&=\log \left(S_{0}\exp \left(\left(\mu -{\frac {\sigma ^{2}}{2}}\right)t+\sigma W_{t}\right)\right)\\[6pt]&=\log(S_{0})+\left(\mu -{\frac {\sigma ^{2}}{2}}\right)t+\sigma W_{t}.\end{alignedat}}}
Taking the expectation yields the same result as above:
E
log
(
S
t
)
=
log
(
S
0
)
+
(
μ
−
σ
2
/
2
)
t
{\displaystyle \operatorname {E} \log(S_{t})=\log(S_{0})+(\mu -\sigma ^{2}/2)t}
.
Simulating sample paths
Multivariate version
GBM can be extended to the case where there are multiple correlated price paths.
Each price path follows the underlying process
d
S
t
i
=
μ
i
S
t
i
d
t
+
σ
i
S
t
i
d
W
t
i
,
{\displaystyle dS_{t}^{i}=\mu _{i}S_{t}^{i}\,dt+\sigma _{i}S_{t}^{i}\,dW_{t}^{i},}
where the Wiener processes are correlated such that
E
(
d
W
t
i
d
W
t
j
)
=
ρ
i
,
j
d
t
{\displaystyle \operatorname {E} (dW_{t}^{i}\,dW_{t}^{j})=\rho _{i,j}\,dt}
where
ρ
i
,
i
=
1
{\displaystyle \rho _{i,i}=1}
.
For the multivariate case, this implies that
Cov
(
S
t
i
,
S
t
j
)
=
S
0
i
S
0
j
e
(
μ
i
+
μ
j
)
t
(
e
ρ
i
,
j
σ
i
σ
j
t
−
1
)
.
{\displaystyle \operatorname {Cov} (S_{t}^{i},S_{t}^{j})=S_{0}^{i}S_{0}^{j}e^{(\mu _{i}+\mu _{j})t}\left(e^{\rho _{i,j}\sigma _{i}\sigma _{j}t}-1\right).}
A multivariate formulation that maintains the driving Brownian motions
W
t
i
{\displaystyle W_{t}^{i}}
independent is
d
S
t
i
=
μ
i
S
t
i
d
t
+
∑
j
=
1
d
σ
i
,
j
S
t
i
d
W
t
j
,
{\displaystyle dS_{t}^{i}=\mu _{i}S_{t}^{i}\,dt+\sum _{j=1}^{d}\sigma _{i,j}S_{t}^{i}\,dW_{t}^{j},}
where the correlation between
S
t
i
{\displaystyle S_{t}^{i}}
and
S
t
j
{\displaystyle S_{t}^{j}}
is now expressed through the
σ
i
,
j
=
ρ
i
,
j
σ
i
σ
j
{\displaystyle \sigma _{i,j}=\rho _{i,j}\,\sigma _{i}\,\sigma _{j}}
terms.
Use in finance
Geometric Brownian motion is used to model stock prices in the Black–Scholes model and is the most widely used model of stock price behavior.
Some of the arguments for using GBM to model stock prices are:
The expected returns of GBM are independent of the value of the process (stock price), which agrees with what we would expect in reality.
A GBM process only assumes positive values, just like real stock prices.
A GBM process shows the same kind of 'roughness' in its paths as we see in real stock prices.
Calculations with GBM processes are relatively easy.
However, GBM is not a completely realistic model, in particular it falls short of reality in the following points:
In real stock prices, volatility changes over time (possibly stochastically), but in GBM, volatility is assumed constant.
In real life, stock prices often show jumps caused by unpredictable events or news, but in GBM, the path is continuous (no discontinuity).
Apart from modeling stock prices, Geometric Brownian motion has also found applications in the monitoring of trading strategies.
Extensions
In an attempt to make GBM more realistic as a model for stock prices, also in relation to the volatility smile problem, one can drop the assumption that the volatility (
σ
{\displaystyle \sigma }
) is constant. If we assume that the volatility is a deterministic function of the stock price and time, this is called a local volatility model. A straightforward extension of the Black Scholes GBM is a local volatility SDE whose distribution is a mixture of distributions of GBM, the lognormal mixture dynamics, resulting in a convex combination of Black Scholes prices for options. If instead we assume that the volatility has a randomness of its own—often described by a different equation driven by a different Brownian Motion—the model is called a stochastic volatility model, see for example the Heston model.
See also
Brownian surface
References
External links
Geometric Brownian motion models for stock movement except in rare events.
Excel Simulation of a Geometric Brownian Motion to simulate Stock Prices
"Interactive Web Application: Stochastic Processes used in Quantitative Finance". Archived from the original on 2015-09-20. Retrieved 2015-07-03.
Non-Newtonian calculus website
Trading Strategy Monitoring: Modeling the PnL as a Geometric Brownian Motion
Kata Kunci Pencarian:
- Geometric Brownian motion
- Itô's lemma
- Brownian motion
- Itô calculus
- Wiener process
- Ergodicity economics
- Black–Scholes equation
- Moneyness
- Brownian ratchet
- GBM