- Source: Giffen good
In microeconomics and consumer theory, a Giffen good is a product that people consume more of as the price rises and vice versa, violating the law of demand.
For ordinary goods, as the price of the good rises, the substitution effect makes consumers purchase less of it, and more of substitute goods; the income effect can either reinforce or weaken this decline in demand, but for an ordinary good never outweighs it. By contrast, a Giffen good is so strongly an inferior good (in higher demand at lower incomes) that the contrary income effect more than offsets the substitution effect, and the net effect of the good's price rise is to increase demand for it. This phenomenon is known as the Giffen paradox.
Background
Giffen goods are named after Scottish economist Sir Robert Giffen, to whom Alfred Marshall attributed this idea in his book Principles of Economics, first published in 1890. Giffen first proposed the paradox from his observations of the purchasing habits of the Victorian era poor.
It has been suggested by Etsusuke Masuda and Peter Newman that Simon Gray described "Gray goods" in his 1815 text entitled The Happiness of States: Or An Inquiry Concerning Population, The Modes of Subsisting and Employing It, and the Effects of All on Human Happiness. The chapter entitled A Rise in the Price of Bread Corn, beyond a certain Pitch, tends to increase the Consumption of it, contains a detailed account of what have come to be called Giffen goods, and which might better be called Gray goods. They also note that George Stigler corrected Marshall's misattribution in a 1947 journal article on the history.
Analysis
For almost all products, the demand curve has a negative slope: as the price increases, quantity demanded for the good decreases. (See Supply and demand for background.)
Giffen goods are the exception to this general rule. Unlike other goods or services, the price point at which supply and demand meet results in higher prices and greater demand whenever market forces recognize a change in supply and demand for Giffen goods. As a result, when price goes up, the quantity demanded also goes up. To be a true Giffen good, the good's price must be the only thing that changes to produce a change in quantity demanded.
Giffen goods should not be confused with Veblen goods: Veblen goods are products whose demand increases if their price increases because the price is seen as an indicator of quality or status.
The classic example given by Marshall is of inferior quality staple foods, whose demand is driven by poverty that makes their purchasers unable to afford superior foodstuffs. As the price of the cheap staple rises, they can no longer afford to supplement their diet with better foods, and must consume more of the staple food.
As Mr. Giffen has pointed out, a rise in the price of bread makes so large a drain on the resources of the poorer labouring families and raises the marginal utility of money to them so much that they are forced to curtail their consumption of meat and the more expensive farinaceous foods: and, bread being still the cheapest food which they can get and will take, they consume more, and not less of it.
There are three necessary conditions for this situation to arise:
the good in question must be an inferior good,
there must be a lack of close substitute goods, and
the goods must constitute a substantial percentage of the buyer's income, but not such a substantial percentage of the buyer's income that none of the associated normal goods are consumed.
If precondition #1 is changed to "The goods in question must be so inferior that the income effect is greater than the substitution effect" then this list defines necessary and sufficient conditions. The last condition is a condition on the buyer rather than the goods itself, and thus the phenomenon is also called a "Giffen behavior".
Examples
Suppose a consumer has a budget of $6 per day that they spend on food. They must eat three meals a day, and there are only two options for them: the inferior good, bread, which costs $1 per meal, and the superior good, cake, which costs $4 per meal. Cake is always preferable to bread. At present, the consumer would purchase 2 loaves of bread and one cake, completely exhausting their budget to fill 3 meals each day. Now, if the price of bread were to rise from $1 to $2, then the consumer would have no choice but to give up cake, and spend their entire budget on 3 loaves of bread, in order to eat three meals a day. In this situation, their consumption of bread would have actually increased as a result of the price increase. Thus bread would be a Giffen good in this example.
Investor Rob Arnott said in 2021 that the stock market is a Giffen good. Widespread interest in the market tends to increase during periods of rising prices for stocks and decrease during market crashes, which is contrary to ideal investing practices.
Empirical evidence
Evidence for the existence of Giffen goods has generally been limited. A 2008 paper by Robert Jensen and Nolan Miller argued rice and wheat noodles were Giffen goods in parts of China. Another 2008 paper by the same authors experimentally demonstrated the existence of Giffen goods among people at the household level by directly subsidizing purchases of rice and wheat flour for extremely poor families. In this paper, the field experiment conducted in 2007 consisted of the province of Hunan, where rice is a dietary staple, and the province of Gansu, where wheat is a staple. In both provinces, random households were selected and were offered their dietary staple at subsidized rates. After the completion of the project, it could be found that the demands from Hunan households who were offered the rice fell drastically. Meanwhile, the demands of wheat in Gansu implies weak evidence of the Giffen paradox.
In 1991, Battalio, Kagel, and Kogut published an article arguing that quinine water is a Giffen good for some lab rats. However, they were only able to show the existence of a Giffen good at an individual level and not the market level.
Giffen goods are difficult to study because the definition requires a number of observable conditions. One reason for the difficulty in studying market demand for Giffen goods is that Giffen originally envisioned a specific situation faced by individuals in poverty. Modern consumer behaviour research methods often deal in aggregates that average out income levels, and are too blunt an instrument to capture these specific situations. Complicating the matter are the requirements that availability of substitutes be limited and that consumers be not so poor that they can only afford the inferior good. For this reason, many text books use the term Giffen paradox rather than Giffen good.
Some types of premium goods (such as expensive French wines, or celebrity-endorsed perfumes) are sometimes called Giffen goods via the claim that lowering the price of these high-status goods decreases demand because they are no longer perceived as exclusive or high-status products. However, to the extent that the perceived nature of such high-status goods actually changes significantly with a substantial price drop, this behavior disqualifies them from being considered Giffen goods, because the Giffen goods analysis assumes that only the consumer's income or the relative price level changes, not the nature of the good itself. If a price change modifies consumers' perception of the good, they should be analysed as Veblen goods. Some economists question the empirical validity of the distinction between Giffen and Veblen goods, arguing that whenever there is a substantial change in the price of a good its perceived nature also changes, since price is a large part of what constitutes a product. However, the theoretical distinction between the two types of analysis remains clear, and which one should apply to any actual case is an empirical matter. Based on microeconomic consumer theory, it assumes that the consumer could value a good without knowing the price. However, when the consumers who were constrained by income and price need to choose the optimal goods, the goods must be valued with available prices. Because, in some degrees, the higher price indicates higher values of goods offering to the consumers.
= Great Famine in Ireland
=Potatoes during the Irish Great Famine were once considered to be an example of a Giffen good. Along with the Famine, the price of potatoes and meat increased subsequently. Compared to meat, it is obvious that potatoes could be much cheaper as a staple food. Due to poverty, individuals could not afford meat anymore; therefore, demand for potatoes increased. Under such a situation, the supply curve will increase with the rise in potatoes’ price, which is consistent with the definition of Giffen good. However, Gerald P. Dwyer and Cotton M. Lindsey challenged this idea in their 1984 article Robert Giffen and the Irish Potato, where they showed the contradicting nature of the Giffen "legend" with respect to historical evidence.
The Giffen nature of the Irish potato was also later discredited by Sherwin Rosen of the University of Chicago in his 1999 paper Potato Paradoxes. Rosen showed that the phenomenon could be explained by a normal demand model.
Charles Read has shown with quantitative evidence that bacon pigs showed Giffen-style behaviour during the Irish Famine, but that potatoes did not.
= Other proposed examples
=Anthony Bopp (1983) proposed that kerosene, a low-quality fuel used in home heating, was a Giffen good. Schmuel Baruch and Yakar Kanai (2001) suggested that shochu, a Japanese distilled beverage, could be a Giffen good. In both cases, the authors offered supporting econometric evidence. However, this evidence is considered incomplete.
It is worth noting that a good may be a Giffen good at the individual level but not at the aggregate level (or vice-versa). As shown by Hildenbrand's model, aggregate demand will not necessarily exhibit any Giffen behavior even when we assume the same preferences for each consumer, whose nominal wealth is uniformly distributed on an interval containing zero. This could explain the presence of Giffen behavior for individual consumers but the absence in aggregate data.
See also
Capital good
Consumer choice
Price elasticity of demand
Supply and demand
Ordinary good
Veblen good
Inferior good
Normal good
References
Further reading
Abramsky, Sasha (October 17, 2005). "Running on Fumes". The Nation. pp. 15–19. Archived from the original on March 5, 2008. Retrieved October 8, 2005.
Jensen, Robert; Miller, Nolan (2008). "Giffen Behavior and Subsistence Consumption". American Economic Review. 98 (4): 1553–77. doi:10.1257/aer.98.4.1553. PMC 2964162. PMID 21031158.
Baruch, Shmuel; Kannai, Yakar (2001). "Inferior Goods, Giffen Goods, and Shochu" (PDF). Economics Essays: 9–17. doi:10.1007/978-3-662-04623-4_3. ISBN 978-3-642-07539-1. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2012-09-04.
Bopp, Anthony (1983). "The Demand for Kerosene: a Modern Giffen Good". Applied Economics. 15 (4): 459–467. doi:10.1080/00036848300000017.
Masuda, Etsusuke; Newman, Peter (1981). "Gray and Giffen Goods". The Economic Journal. 91 (364): 1011–1014. doi:10.2307/2232507. JSTOR 2232507.
Stigler, George (1947). "Notes on the History of the Giffen Paradox". Journal of Political Economy. 55 (2): 154. doi:10.1086/256487. JSTOR 1825304.
Yamagishi, Jumpei; Hatakeyama, Tetsuhiro (2021). "Microeconomics of Metabolism: The Warburg Effect as Giffen Behaviour". Bulletin of Mathematical Biology. 83 (12): 120. doi:10.1007/s11538-021-00952-x. PMC 8558188. PMID 34718881.
External links
Alfred Marshall Principles of Economics Bk.III,Ch.VI in paragraph III.VI.17
The Last Word on Giffen Goods? Archived 2015-12-08 at the Wayback Machine
Giffen good
What Do Prostitutes and Rice Have in Common?
Kata Kunci Pencarian:
- Ed, Edd n Eddy (musim 5)
- Daftar episode Ed, Edd n Eddy
- Giffen good
- Inferior good
- Law of demand
- Ordinary good
- Veblen good
- Ersatz good
- Robert Giffen
- Normal good
- Giffen
- Paradox