- Source: Supermodular function
In mathematics, a function
f
:
R
k
→
R
{\displaystyle f\colon \mathbb {R} ^{k}\to \mathbb {R} }
is supermodular if
f
(
x
↑
y
)
+
f
(
x
↓
y
)
≥
f
(
x
)
+
f
(
y
)
{\displaystyle f(x\uparrow y)+f(x\downarrow y)\geq f(x)+f(y)}
for all
x
{\displaystyle x}
,
y
∈
R
k
{\displaystyle y\in \mathbb {R} ^{k}}
, where
x
↑
y
{\displaystyle x\uparrow y}
denotes the componentwise maximum and
x
↓
y
{\displaystyle x\downarrow y}
the componentwise minimum of
x
{\displaystyle x}
and
y
{\displaystyle y}
.
If −f is supermodular then f is called submodular, and if the inequality is changed to an equality the function is modular.
If f is twice continuously differentiable, then supermodularity is equivalent to the condition
∂
2
f
∂
z
i
∂
z
j
≥
0
for all
i
≠
j
.
{\displaystyle {\frac {\partial ^{2}f}{\partial z_{i}\,\partial z_{j}}}\geq 0{\mbox{ for all }}i\neq j.}
Supermodularity in economics and game theory
The concept of supermodularity is used in the social sciences to analyze how one agent's decision affects the incentives of others.
Consider a symmetric game with a smooth payoff function
f
{\displaystyle \,f}
defined over actions
z
i
{\displaystyle \,z_{i}}
of two or more players
i
∈
1
,
2
,
…
,
N
{\displaystyle i\in {1,2,\dots ,N}}
. Suppose the action space is continuous; for simplicity, suppose each action is chosen from an interval:
z
i
∈
[
a
,
b
]
{\displaystyle z_{i}\in [a,b]}
. In this context, supermodularity of
f
{\displaystyle \,f}
implies that an increase in player
i
{\displaystyle \,i}
's choice
z
i
{\displaystyle \,z_{i}}
increases the marginal payoff
d
f
/
d
z
j
{\displaystyle df/dz_{j}}
of action
z
j
{\displaystyle \,z_{j}}
for all other players
j
{\displaystyle \,j}
. That is, if any player
i
{\displaystyle \,i}
chooses a higher
z
i
{\displaystyle \,z_{i}}
, all other players
j
{\displaystyle \,j}
have an incentive to raise their choices
z
j
{\displaystyle \,z_{j}}
too. Following the terminology of Bulow, Geanakoplos, and Klemperer (1985), economists call this situation strategic complementarity, because players' strategies are complements to each other. This is the basic property underlying examples of multiple equilibria in coordination games.
The opposite case of supermodularity of
f
{\displaystyle \,f}
, called submodularity, corresponds to the situation of strategic substitutability. An increase in
z
i
{\displaystyle \,z_{i}}
lowers the marginal payoff to all other player's choices
z
j
{\displaystyle \,z_{j}}
, so strategies are substitutes. That is, if
i
{\displaystyle \,i}
chooses a higher
z
i
{\displaystyle \,z_{i}}
, other players have an incentive to pick a lower
z
j
{\displaystyle \,z_{j}}
.
For example, Bulow et al. consider the interactions of many imperfectly competitive firms. When an increase in output by one firm raises the marginal revenues of the other firms, production decisions are strategic complements. When an increase in output by one firm lowers the marginal revenues of the other firms, production decisions are strategic substitutes.
A supermodular utility function is often related to complementary goods. However, this view is disputed.
Submodular functions of subsets
Supermodularity and submodularity are also defined for functions defined over subsets of a larger set. Intuitively, a submodular function over the subsets demonstrates "diminishing returns". There are specialized techniques for optimizing submodular functions.
Let S be a finite set. A function
f
:
2
S
→
R
{\displaystyle f\colon 2^{S}\to \mathbb {R} }
is submodular if for any
A
⊂
B
⊂
S
{\displaystyle A\subset B\subset S}
and
x
∈
S
∖
B
{\displaystyle x\in S\setminus B}
,
f
(
A
∪
{
x
}
)
−
f
(
A
)
≥
f
(
B
∪
{
x
}
)
−
f
(
B
)
{\displaystyle f(A\cup \{x\})-f(A)\geq f(B\cup \{x\})-f(B)}
. For supermodularity, the inequality is reversed.
The definition of submodularity can equivalently be formulated as
f
(
A
)
+
f
(
B
)
≥
f
(
A
∩
B
)
+
f
(
A
∪
B
)
{\displaystyle f(A)+f(B)\geq f(A\cap B)+f(A\cup B)}
for all subsets A and B of S.
Theory and enumeration algorithms for finding local and global maxima (minima) of submodular (supermodular) functions can be found in "Maximization of submodular functions: Theory and enumeration algorithms", B. Goldengorin.
See also
Pseudo-Boolean function
Topkis's theorem
Submodular set function
Superadditive
Utility functions on indivisible goods
Notes and references
Kata Kunci Pencarian:
- Supermodular function
- Submodular set function
- Index of economics articles
- FKG inequality
- Utility functions on indivisible goods
- Paul Milgrom
- Knaster–Tarski theorem
- Strategic complements
- Topkis's theorem
- Fuzzy measure theory
Robot Dreams (2023)
No More Posts Available.
No more pages to load.